e-GMAT Logo
NEUR
N

Credit in developing countries can be granted through formal or informal channels. Formal channels include institutions such as banks, credit...

GMAT Multi Source Reasoning : (MSR) Questions

Source: Official Guide
Multi Source Reasoning
Case Study
HARD
...
...
Notes
Post a Query
Credit Discussion
Loans Table
Interest Rates

Credit in developing countries can be granted through formal or informal channels. Formal channels include institutions such as banks, credit cooperatives, and government agencies. Loans of this type accrue positive interest and are typically court enforced. Informal credit channels include relatives, friends, community members, moneylenders, rotating savings and credit associations, and informal intermediaries. Loans such as these may or may not accrue positive interest. Loans of either type may be used by the borrower for consumption or investment in a business.

In 1930s rural China, informal credit was sometimes court enforced. However, it was more often self-enforcing, especially in remote areas. With a positive-interest rate loan, the borrower would pay principal and interest. With a zero-interest rate loan, the borrower would repay the principal and provide some non-monetary resource in lieu of interest. For example, the borrower might have supplied land, labor, or draft animal services to the lender.

Ques. 1/3

According to the information provided, a lender who offered one of the zero–interest rate loans included in the table would accurately be described as making which of the following trade-offs? Select Yes for each option that applies. Otherwise, select No.

A
Yes
No

Giving up a fixed duration of repayment in exchange for security

B
Yes
No

Giving up interest payments in exchange for security

C
Yes
No

Giving up interest payments in exchange for access to other resources

Solution

OWNING THE DATASET

Understanding Source A: Text Source - Credit Discussion about Developing Countries

Information from Dataset Analysis
"Formal channels include institutions such as banks, credit cooperatives, and government agencies. Loans of this type accrue positive interest and are typically court enforced."
  • Formal credit comes from official institutions and always charges interest
  • These loans have legal backing through courts
  • Inference: Formal credit is more structured and legally protected
"Informal credit channels include relatives, friends, community members, moneylenders, rotating savings and credit associations, and informal intermediaries. Loans such as these may or may not accrue positive interest."
  • Informal credit comes from personal relationships and community members
  • Interest charges are flexible - some charge interest, some don't
  • Inference: Informal credit is more flexible than formal channels
"In 1930s rural China, informal credit was sometimes court enforced. However, it was more often self-enforcing, especially in remote areas."
  • Even informal loans could have legal protection
  • Remote areas relied on community/social pressure for enforcement
  • Inference: Geographic location affected how loans were enforced
"With a zero–interest rate loan, the borrower would repay the principal and provide some non-monetary resource in lieu of interest. For example, the borrower might have supplied land, labor, or draft animal services to the lender."
  • Zero-interest loans weren't actually "free" - borrowers paid in services instead of money
  • Examples include letting lender use their land, working for them, or lending farm animals
  • Inference: These arrangements possibly strengthened community bonds through reciprocal services

Summary: Credit in developing countries operates through formal institutions (always charging interest with legal enforcement) and informal relationships (flexible interest with community-based enforcement), with 1930s rural China showing how zero-interest loans involved non-monetary compensation like labor or land use.


Understanding Source B: Table - 1936 Survey Data from 21 Villages

Information from Dataset Analysis
"A loan involves security if and only if it involves a written (as opposed to a verbal) contract, the presence of a third-party guarantor, or collateral."
  • Security means any formal protection for the lender
  • Three ways to secure a loan: written contract, guarantor, or collateral
  • Inference: Verbal agreements are considered unsecured
Zero Interest: 363 loans
Positive Interest: 300 loans
  • More zero-interest loans than positive-interest loans in these villages
  • Inference: Significant informal lending activity
  • Linkage to Source A: Confirms Source A's statement that informal loans "may or may not accrue positive interest"
Security measures:
Written: 1.4% vs 10.3%
Third Party: 2.8% vs 12.7%
Collateral: 1.4% vs 10.3%
  • Positive-interest loans are 7-9 times more likely to have security
  • Zero-interest loans operate mostly on trust
  • Inference: Zero-interest loans rely on informal enforcement
  • Linkage to Source A: Aligns with Source A's description of self-enforcing loans in rural areas
Fixed duration: 25.3% vs 51.3%
  • Half of positive-interest loans have defined repayment periods
  • Only a quarter of zero-interest loans have fixed terms
  • Inference: Formal structure correlates with interest charges
Purpose:
Consumption: 62.0% vs 58.7%
Investment: 33.1% vs 38.0%
  • Both loan types primarily used for daily needs (consumption)
  • About one-third used for business/investment
  • Linkage to Source A: Validates Source A's mention that loans are used for "consumption or investment"
Seasonality shows peaks in Jan-Mar (32.5% and 38.7%) and Oct-Dec (33.6% and 31.3%)
  • Lending concentrated at year's beginning and end
  • Summer months (July-Sep) show lowest activity
  • Inference: Possibly related to agricultural cycles or cultural events

Summary: The 1936 data confirms Source A's framework, showing zero-interest loans outnumbered positive-interest loans (363 vs 300), with positive-interest loans having significantly more security measures and fixed terms, while both types served primarily consumption needs with similar seasonal patterns.


Understanding Source C: Scatter Plot - Village-Level Interest Rate Analysis

Chart Analysis:

  • Shows relationship between percentage of zero-interest loans in a village and that village's average annual interest rate
  • Each dot represents one of the 21 villages from Source B's survey
  • Key patterns observed: Clear downward trend - villages with more zero-interest loans have lower average interest rates
  • Average interest rates range from approximately 15% to 60% annually
  • Percentage of zero-interest loans varies widely by village (roughly 20% to 90%)
  • Inference: Villages have distinct lending cultures - some heavily favor zero-interest loans while others prefer interest-bearing loans
  • Linkage to Source A: Villages with high zero-interest percentages likely rely more on the non-monetary compensation system (labor, land use) described in Source A
  • Linkage to Source B: While Source B shows overall totals (363 zero-interest vs 300 positive-interest), Source C reveals this varies dramatically by village

Summary: Village-level data reveals significant geographic variation in lending practices, with some villages having up to 90% zero-interest loans (using non-monetary compensation) while others favor interest-bearing loans, creating average interest rates ranging from 15-60% annually across the 21 villages.


Overall Summary

  • The 1930s rural Chinese credit system operated through two parallel tracks: zero-interest loans using non-monetary compensation (labor, land use, draft animals) and positive-interest loans with more formal security measures
  • Zero-interest loans slightly outnumbered positive-interest loans overall (363 vs 300), but this varied dramatically by village - some villages had mostly zero-interest lending while others favored cash-based interest
  • Both loan types served primarily consumption needs (about 60%), with lending activity concentrated in certain seasons
  • Villages developed distinct credit cultures visible in their lending patterns, with those favoring zero-interest loans showing much lower average interest rates overall

Question Analysis

The question asks lenders who gave zero-interest loans to evaluate which trade-offs they made. We need to determine whether each statement correctly describes what they gave up and what they received in return. This requires a comparative evaluation of trade-off descriptions with a Yes/No selection for each option.

Key constraints:

  • Focus on zero-interest loan lenders
  • Identify accurate trade-offs
  • Select Yes/No for each option

Connecting to Our Analysis

The analysis contains detailed information about zero-interest vs positive-interest loans including security measures, fixed duration percentages, and Source A's explanation of non-monetary compensation for zero-interest loans. All needed information to answer this question is available in the collated analysis.

Extracting Relevant Findings

We are comparing zero-interest loan characteristics against each proposed trade-off. Key findings show:

  • Zero-interest loans: 1.4% written contracts, 2.8% third party involvement, 1.4% collateral, 25.3% fixed duration
  • Source A explains these loans provided non-monetary resources (land, labor, draft animals) instead of interest
  • Each statement proposes a different trade-off for zero-interest lenders

Individual Statement/Option Evaluations

Statement 1 Evaluation

Did lenders give up fixed repayment schedules to get more security?

  • Zero-interest loans have 25.3% fixed duration with minimal security (1.4-2.8%)
  • Positive-interest loans have 51.3% fixed duration with higher security (10.3-12.7%)
  • Zero-interest loans have both lower fixed duration and lower security
  • This is incorrect because they didn't trade fixed duration for security; they have less of both

Statement 2 Evaluation

Did lenders give up interest payments to get more security?

  • Zero-interest loans have no interest with minimal security (1.4-2.8%)
  • Positive-interest loans have interest with higher security (10.3-12.7%)
  • Zero-interest loans gave up interest but got less security, not more
  • This is incorrect because they gave up interest but received less security, not more

Statement 3 Evaluation

Did lenders give up interest payments to get access to other resources?

  • Zero-interest loans provided no cash interest but received land, labor, or draft animal services
  • Source A explicitly states borrowers provided non-monetary resources in lieu of interest
  • Zero-interest lenders received valuable non-cash compensation
  • This is correct because Source A confirms they exchanged interest for other resources

Systematic Checking

Verifying each trade-off against the comprehensive data:

  • Statement 1 fails because zero-interest loans have less of both fixed duration AND security
  • Statement 2 fails because giving up interest resulted in less security, not more
  • Statement 3 succeeds because Source A explicitly describes the non-monetary compensation system
  • The data shows zero-interest loans operated on trust and reciprocity with alternative compensation

Final Answer

  • Statement 1: No
  • Statement 2: No
  • Statement 3: Yes
Answer Choices Explained
A
Yes
No

Giving up a fixed duration of repayment in exchange for security

B
Yes
No

Giving up interest payments in exchange for security

C
Yes
No

Giving up interest payments in exchange for access to other resources

Rate this Solution
Tell us what you think about this solution
...
...
Forum Discussions
Start a new discussion
Post
Load More
Similar Questions
Finding similar questions...
Previous Attempts
Loading attempts...
Similar Questions
Finding similar questions...
Parallel Question Generator
Create AI-generated questions with similar patterns to master this question type.